Labour compensation and productivity in the EU-27 and Greece

Agora Contributor: Bob Traa & Jens Bastian
Photo by Giannis Papanikos/Fosphotos
Photo by Giannis Papanikos/Fosphotos

Blog 5 addressed the conundrum that in Greece the pace of hiring in the public sector exceeds that of hiring in the private sector. Blog 6 compared average productivity growth per employee in the public and private sectors since 2000, and found that public employees, on average, have had negative productivity growth, whereas private sector employees have had positive, but low, productivity growth. This blog 7 concludes our three-part series on the crucial items of productivity and productivity growth by adding a further characteristic, namely comparing productivity per hour worked in the EU-27 and in Greece, and linking this to wages.

In blog 6 we noted that measuring productivity in the public sector is not straightforward, because governments do not produce and promote their output in contested markets where the interaction of demand and supply sets prices. Private sector business firms do compete on quality and prices in such markets, domestically as well as internationally. This “market test” is important in order to find out what firms are efficient and productive, and those that are not.

What we have to be aware of, in this context, is that productivity is measured either on the basis of “output” or “input” indicators. For the private sector, productivity indicators are almost always based on output measurements, i.e., real value added and prices in the free market. In the government sector, since output is not marketed as in the private sector, the real value added measures are largely based on input data.

To be precise, the wage bill is a crucial input for value added measured in the government sector. After all, value added, or real GDP, is first measured from the “production side,” and can then be divided alternatively into wages, profits, and a small sliver of indirect taxes minus subsidies. Such calculation is the approach used for the national accounts from the “income side.” The production--or supply--side tells us how much has been produced. The income side tells us how the income proceeds from all this production have been distributed. These two measures need to be the same as real GDP for the entire economy.[1]

Gross value added, as measured for governments, uses the wage bill as a crucial input indicator of how much value added the government “produces” in total. It can thus be that if the government decides to give all civil servants a hefty wage increase, that “income” from government, and hence gross value added “produced” by the government increases: “productivity” has increased simply because of a wage increase. In the private sector the mechanics are different. A (sudden) wage increase would likely be offset by lower profits and only the distribution of income would change, not output per person or productivity.

Yet, we would argue that even in the public sector, in the long run and as a general equilibrium condition, the government is also subject to market based checks and balances. The political system cannot just increase government wages willy-nilly and believe that there are no (upward) limits. As we have argued before, governments “compete” across international borders, especially in free markets for goods and labor such as in the US and the EU.

If remuneration in government were to be excessive for a long period of time, then the inefficiencies of these government policies would impose a cost on society as a whole and structural economic performance would deteriorate. Poor governance and policies of this sort may lead businesses and talented young people to leave the country to market their skills elsewhere--they thus vote with their feet. Greece is seeing some of these effects. The country is struggling with a long process of finding a good equilibrium for government, government compensation, and governing labor and product markets. The adjustment undertaken so far is incomplete.

Another anchor in our thinking about productivity and remuneration is that eventually, wages reflect productivity. And wage growth reflects productivity growth. Models show that business firms and, we would argue governments, cannot remunerate in a way that is divorced from productivity per employee or (more precise) per hour(-s) worked. Thus, we can think of the productivity developments in a way “upside down”--they tell us something about (sustainable) wage developments in the country. Over time, wages and productivity are two sides of the same coin. This brings us to comparing productivity per hour worked in the EU-27 and in Greece. All data provided are from Eurostat, which facilitates the comparisons.

Consider Figures 1a and 1b below. These show the productivity in real euros (reference year 2015) as measured by gross value added in the national accounts per hour worked. All data are quarterly and adjusted for seasonality and differences in working-days. Thereby Eurostat is giving us a rather precise measure of productivity. In equilibrium, this “productivity per hour worked” can be interpreted as “sustainable wages per hour worked.”

We see that in the EU-27, on average, real productivity per hour worked (“real sustainable wages”) in the economy as a whole have increased between 2000-2020 by about 1.1 percent compounded annual rate, from almost 28 euros in 2000 to just over 35 euros per hour worked in 2020. In the private sector the increase has been 1.4 percent a year, and in the government sector the increase has been 0.1 percent a year. The dip in the Great Recession of 2009-2010 is clearly visible (the damage from the recession); the dip in the Covid-19 pandemic in 2020 is also visible but is less pronounced so far. What is interesting in this figure is that real wages in government, on average, really have not moved much. This different trend is not sustainable in the long run, because governments need to be able to attract good productive employees. Currently, there is a large premium on working for the private sector, rather than for the government. The EU economy overall is moving along relatively steadily.

In contrast, the same figure for Greece is quite different and indicates quite a bit of turmoil over time. In Greece, the government sector paid much higher salaries in the 2000s than the private sector (average of around 25 euros per hour, versus 20 euros per hour in the private sector). The Greek crisis (2009ff) brought wage cuts in the public sector, but “wages” as measured by “productivity per hour” remained above those in the private sector even in the 2010s. In 2020, during the Corona episode, hours worked in Greece in Q2 plummeted so that the measure of productivity spiked up (the opposite effect from what has been observed in the EU-27 as a whole). Very slowly, productivity measures in the public and private sectors, per hour worked, are now converging.

Our interpretation of this turmoil is that Greece entered the euro zone as an uncompetitive, and hence unsustainable, economy. This economic modus operandi crashed in the crisis of 2009-2016. A very slow recovery has set in since 2016, but the relativities between the private and public sectors in Greece are still at great variance with what happened in the EU-27 as a whole. The public sector is paid as well as the private sector, so there is no reason to expect that the private sector attracts more employees than the public sector. Indeed, if one takes job stability into account, etc., then the public sector still must be quite attractive relative to the private sector in Greece, as hiring trends confirm.

Productivity per hour worked, or real “sustainable wages” in the government sector in Greece has declined by 1.6 percent annual average between 2000 and 2020, to around 18 euros. In the private sector, productivity per hour, or “sustainable wages” have increased by 0.3 percent a year on average (much less than in the  EU-27 private sector on average, but slightly above the EU-27 government sector on average).

Finally, we can facilitate the comparison between Greece and its partner countries in the EU-27 side by side in Figures 2a-2c above. In Figure 2a we see that Greece is not as productive as the EU-27 as a whole. Therefore, Greece cannot have the same per-capita income as the EU-27 as a whole. One hopes that convergence will pull Greece into becoming more productive while the EU-27 does not slip over time. Income transfers cannot bridge this difference in a sustainable way. The absorption rate of structural funds will need to improve further. The transparent and efficient utilization of the unprecedented financial resources stemming from the EU’s Recovery and Resilience Fund (RFF) will be critical in the coming years. Positive outcomes depend primarily on the Greek political system and corporate governance capacity of the business sector.

It is also striking that in the early 2000s, even though Greece overall was 33 percent less productive than the EU-27 overall, pay in the government sector was almost at par with that in the EU-27 overall (Figure 2c). In 2020, Greece overall was almost 50 percent as productive as the EU-27 and the difference in the government sector is roughly a 45 percent gap. Put otherwise, there has been relative convergence.

If Greece is to do well within the EU partner group, then productivity growth in the private sector needs to speed up, and labor allocation needs to switch from predominantly to the public sector to predominantly the free and contested private sector. This requires product market reforms and stronger governance for more competitive internal markets. Greece has initiated significant labor market reforms since 2010, but not enough as regards product market reforms or governance reforms.

These are the crucial tasks of the current conservative government that services public employees, larger private corporations, and higher income earners as its primary voter clientele. If Greece can catch up in productivity with the EU-27 and start narrowing the difference that has been growing in the 2010s, then talented young Greeks will stay in or even return to Greece and better dynamic developments of the economy will prevail. That will be the big long-term payoff of reforms in product markets and the government sector.

*Bob Traa is a macroeconomist and author of "The Macroeconomy of Greece: Odysseus' Plan for the Long Journey Back to Debt Sustainability" published in 2020. Jens Bastian is senior policy advisor at ELIAMEP.


[1] A third measure of real GDP is from the “aggregate demand side,” or how GDP is absorbed in the demand components of consumption, investment, exports, and imports. All three measures of nominal and real GDP--supply, demand, and income--are equal in total to overall nominal and real GDP.

 

0 Comment(s)

Please Comment

You have to
in order to add a comment.